欢迎来到装配图网! | 帮助中心 装配图网zhuangpeitu.com!
装配图网
ImageVerifierCode 换一换
首页 装配图网 > 资源分类 > PPT文档下载
 

微观经济学英文课件:ch09 The Analysis of Competitive Markets

  • 资源ID:190599563       资源大小:2.45MB        全文页数:28页
  • 资源格式: PPT        下载积分:30积分
快捷下载 游客一键下载
会员登录下载
微信登录下载
三方登录下载: 微信开放平台登录 支付宝登录   QQ登录   微博登录  
二维码
微信扫一扫登录
下载资源需要30积分
邮箱/手机:
温馨提示:
用户名和密码都是您填写的邮箱或者手机号,方便查询和重复下载(系统自动生成)
支付方式: 支付宝    微信支付   
验证码:   换一换

 
账号:
密码:
验证码:   换一换
  忘记密码?
    
友情提示
2、PDF文件下载后,可能会被浏览器默认打开,此种情况可以点击浏览器菜单,保存网页到桌面,就可以正常下载了。
3、本站不支持迅雷下载,请使用电脑自带的IE浏览器,或者360浏览器、谷歌浏览器下载即可。
4、本站资源下载后的文档和图纸-无水印,预览文档经过压缩,下载后原文更清晰。
5、试题试卷类文档,如果标题没有明确说明有答案则都视为没有答案,请知晓。

微观经济学英文课件:ch09 The Analysis of Competitive Markets

Fernando&Yvonn QuijanoPrepared by:The Analysisof CompetitiveMarkets9C H A P T E RCopyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets2 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.CHAPTER 9 OUTLINE9.1 Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government PoliciesConsumer and Producer Surplus9.2 The Efficiency of a Competitive Market9.3 Minimum Prices9.4 Price Supports and Production Quotas9.5 Import Quotas and Tariffs9.6 The Impact of a Tax or SubsidyChapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets3 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.EVALUATING THE GAINS AND LOSSESFROM GOVERNMENT POLICIESCONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS9.1Review of Consumer and Producer SurplusConsumer A would pay$10 for a good whose market price is$5 and therefore enjoys a benefit of$5.Consumer B enjoys a benefit of$2,and Consumer C,who values the good at exactly the market price,enjoys no benefit.Consumer surplus,which measures the total benefit to all consumers,is the yellow-shaded area between the demand curve and the market price.Consumer and Producer SurplusFigure 9.1Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets4 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.EVALUATING THE GAINS AND LOSSESFROM GOVERNMENT POLICIESCONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS9.1Review of Consumer and Producer SurplusProducer surplus measures the total profits of producers,plus rents to factor inputs.It is the benefit that lower-cost producers enjoy by selling at the market price,shown by the green-shaded area between the supply curve and the market price.Together,consumer and producer surplus measure the welfare benefit of a competitive market.Consumer and Producer Surplus(continued)Figure 9.1Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets5 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.EVALUATING THE GAINS AND LOSSESFROM GOVERNMENT POLICIESCONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS9.1Application of Consumer and Producer Surplus welfare effects Gains and losses to consumers and producers.The price of a good has been regulated to be no higher than Pmax,which is below the market-clearing price P0.The gain to consumers is the difference between rectangle A and triangle B.The loss to producers is the sum of rectangle A and triangle C.Triangles B and C together measure the deadweight loss from price controls.Change in Consumer and Producer Surplus from Price ControlsFigure 9.2 deadweight loss Net loss of total(consumer plus producer)surplus.Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets6 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.EVALUATING THE GAINS AND LOSSESFROM GOVERNMENT POLICIESCONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS9.1Application of Consumer and Producer SurplusIf demand is sufficiently inelastic,triangle B can be larger than rectangle A.In this case,consumers suffer a net loss from price controls.Effect of Price Controls When Demand Is InelasticFigure 9.3Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets7 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.EVALUATING THE GAINS AND LOSSES FROM GOVERNMENT POLICIESCONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS9.1Supply:QS=15.90+0.72PG+0.05PODemand:QD=10.35 0.18PG+0.69POThe market-clearing price of natural gas is$6.40 per mcf,and the(hypothetical)maximum allowable price is$3.00.A shortage of 23.6 20.6=3.0 Tcf results.The gain to consumers is rectangle A minus triangle B,and the loss to producers is rectangle A plus triangle C.The deadweight loss is the sum of triangles B plus C.Effects of Natural Gas Price ControlsFigure 9.4Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets8 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.THE EFFICIENCY OF A COMPETITIVE MARKET9.2Market FailureThere are two important instances in which market failure can occur:1.Externalities2.Lack of Information economic efficiency Maximization of aggregate consumer and producer surplus.market failure Situation in which an unregulated competitive market is inefficient because prices fail to provide proper signals to consumers and producers.externality Action taken by either a producer or a consumer which affects other producers or consumers but is not accounted for by the market price.Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets9 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.THE EFFICIENCY OF A COMPETITIVE MARKET9.2When price is regulated to be no lower than P2,only Q3 will be demanded.If Q3 is produced,the deadweight loss is given by triangles B and C.At price P2,producers would like to produce more than Q3.If they do,the deadweight loss will be even larger.Welfare Loss When Price is Held Above Market-Clearing LevelFigure 9.5Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets10 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.THE EFFICIENCY OF A COMPETITIVE MARKET9.2Supply:QS=16,000+0.4PDemand:QD=32,0000.4PThe market-clearing price is$20,000;at this price,about 24,000 kidneys per year would be supplied.The law effectively makes the price zero.About 16,000 kidneys per year are still donated;this constrained supply is shown as S.The loss to suppliers is given by rectangle A and triangle C.If consumers received kidneys at no cost,their gain would be given by rectangle A less triangle B.The Market for Kidneys and the Effect of the National Organ Transplantation ActFigure 9.6Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets11 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.THE EFFICIENCY OF A COMPETITIVE MARKET9.2Supply:QS=16,000+0.4PDemand:QD=32,0000.4PIn practice,kidneys are often rationed on the basis of willingness to pay,and many recipients pay most or all of the$40,000 price that clears the market when supply is constrained.Rectangles A and D measure the total value of kidneys when supply is constrained.The Market for Kidneys and the Effect of the National Organ Transplantation Act(continued)Figure 9.6Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets12 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.MINIMUM PRICES9.3Price is regulated to be no lower than Pmin.Producers would like to supply Q2,but consumers will buy only Q3.If producers indeed produce Q2,the amount Q2 Q3 will go unsold and the change in producer surplus will be A C D.In this case,producers as a group may be worse off.Welfare Loss When Price is Held Above Market-Clearing LevelFigure 9.7Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets13 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.MINIMUM PRICES9.3Although the market-clearing wage is w0,firms are not allowed to pay less than wmin.This results in unemployment of an amount L2 L1and a deadweight loss given by triangles B and C.The Minimum WageFigure 9.8Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets14 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.MINIMUM PRICES9.3At price Pmin,airlines would like to supply Q2,well above the quantity Q1 that consumers will buy.Here they supply Q3.Trapezoid D is the cost of unsold output.Airline profits may have been lower as a result of regulation because triangle C and trapezoid D can together exceed rectangle A.In addition,consumers lose A+B.Effect of Airline Regulation by the Civil Aeronautics BoardFigure 9.9Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets15 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.MINIMUM PRICES9.3TABLE 9.1 Airline Industry Data1975198019851990199520002005 Number of Carriers366310270969490Passenger Load Factor54586162677278Passenger Mile Rate(Constant 1995 dollars).218.210.165.150.129.118.092Real Cost Index(1995=100)10112211110910010193Real Fuel Cost Index(1995=100)249300204163100125237Real Cost Index Corrected for Fuel Cost Changes717388951009667By 1981,the airline industry had been completely deregulated.Since that time,many new airlines have begun service,others have gone out of business,and price competition has become much more intense.Because airlines have no control over oil prices,it is more informative to examine a“corrected”real cost index which removes the effects of changing fuel costs.Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets16 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.PRICE SUPPORTS AND PRODUCTION QUOTAS9.4To maintain a price Ps above the market-clearing price P0,the government buys a quantity Qg.The gain to producers is A+B+D.The loss to consumers is A+B.The cost to the government is the speckled rectangle,the area of which is Ps(Q2 Q1).Prince SupportsFigure 9.10 price support Price set by government above free market level and maintained by governmental purchases of excess supply.Total change in welfare:CS+PS Cost to Govt.=D (Q2 Q1)PsPrice SupportsChapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets17 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.PRICE SUPPORTS AND PRODUCTION QUOTAS9.4To maintain a price Ps above the market-clearing price P0,the government can restrict supply to Q1,either by imposing production quotas(as with taxicab medallions)or by giving producers a financial incentive to reduce output(as with acreage limitations in agriculture).For an incentive to work,it must be at least as large as B+C+D,which would be the additional profit earned by planting,given the higher price Ps.The cost to the government is therefore at least B+C+D.Supply RestrictionsFigure 9.11Welfare=A B+A+B+D B C D=B CPrice QuotasCS=A BPS=A C+Payments for not producing(or at least B+C+D)Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets18 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.PRICE SUPPORTS AND PRODUCTION QUOTAS9.41981 Supply:QS=1800+240P1981 Demand:QD=3550 266PTo increase the price to$3.70,the government must buy a quantity of wheat Qg.By buying 122 million bushels of wheat,the government increased the market-clearing price from$3.46 per bushel to$3.70.The Wheat Market in 1981Figure 9.121981 Total demand:QD=3550 266P+QgQg=506P 1750Qg=(506)(3.70)1750=112 million bushelsLoss to consumers=A B=$624 millionCost to the government=$3.70 x 112 million=$451.4 millionTotal cost of the program=$624 million+$451.4 million=$1075 millionGain to producers=A+B+C=$638 millionChapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets19 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.PRICE SUPPORTS AND PRODUCTION QUOTAS9.41985 Supply:QS=1800+240P1985 Demand:QD=2580 194PIn 1985,the demand for wheat was much lower than in 1981,because the market-clearing price was only$1.80.To increase the price to$3.20,the government bought 466 million bushels and also imposed a production quota of 2425 million bushels.The Wheat Market in 1985Figure 9.132425 =2580 194P+QgQg=155+194PQg=155+194($3.20)=466 million bushelsCost to the government=$3.20 x 466 million=$1491 millionChapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets20 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.IMPORT QUOTAS AND TARIFFS9.5In a free market,the domestic price equals the world price Pw.A total Qd is consumed,of which Qs is supplied domestically and the rest imported.When imports are eliminated,the price is increased to P0.The gain to producers is trapezoid A.The loss to consumers is A+B+C,so the deadweight loss is B+C.Import Tariff or Quota That Eliminates ImportsFigure 9.14 import quota Limit on the quantity of a good that can be imported.tariff Tax on an imported good.Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets21 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.IMPORT QUOTAS AND TARIFFS9.5When imports are reduced,the domestic price is increased from Pw to P*.This can be achieved by a quota,or by a tariff T=P*Pw.Trapezoid A is again the gain to domestic producers.The loss to consumers is A+B+C+D.If a tariff is used,the government gains D,the revenue from the tariff.The net domestic loss is B+C.If a quota is used instead,rectangle D becomes part of the profits of foreign producers,and the net domestic loss is B+C+D.Import Tariff or Quota(General Case)Figure 9.15Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets22 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.IMPORT QUOTAS AND TARIFFS9.5U.S.supply:QS=7.48+0.84PU.S.demand:QD=26.7 0.23PAt the world price of 12 cents per pound,about 23.9 billion pounds of sugar would have been consumed in the United States in 2005,of which all but 2.6 billion pounds would have been imported.Restricting imports to 5.3 billion pounds caused the U.S.price to go up by 15 cents.Sugar Quota in 2005Figure 9.16Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets23 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.IMPORT QUOTAS AND TARIFFS9.5U.S.supply:QS=7.48+0.84PU.S.demand:QD=26.7 0.23PThe gain to domestic producers was trapezoid A,about$1.3 billion.Rectangle D,$795 million,was a gain to those foreign producers who obtained quota allotments.Triangles B and C represent the deadweight loss of about$1.2 billion.The cost to consumers,A+B+C+D,was about$3.3 billion.Sugar Quota in 2005(continued)Figure 9.16Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets24 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.THE IMPACT OF A TAX OR SUBSIDY9.6Pb is the price(including the tax)paid by buyers.Ps is the price that sellers receive,less the tax.Here the burden of the tax is split evenly between buyers and sellers.Buyers lose A+B.Sellers lose D+C.The government earns A+D in revenue.The deadweight loss is B+C.Incidence of a TaxFigure 9.17 specific tax Tax of a certain amount of money per unit sold.Market clearing requires four conditions to be satisfied after the tax is in place:QD=QD(Pb)(9.1a)QS=QS(Ps)(9.1b)QD=QS(9.1c)Pb Ps=t(9.1d)Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets25 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.THE IMPACT OF A TAX OR SUBSIDY9.6If demand is very inelastic relative to supply,the burden of the tax falls mostly on buyers.Impact of a Tax Depends on Elasticities of Supply and DemandFigure 9.18If demand is very elastic relative to supply,it falls mostly on sellers.Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets26 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.THE IMPACT OF A TAX OR SUBSIDY9.6A subsidy can be thought of as a negative tax.Like a tax,the benefit of a subsidy is split between buyers and sellers,depending on the relative elasticities of supply and demand.SubsidyFigure 9.19The Effects of a SubsidyConditions needed for the market to clear with a subsidy:QD=QD(Pb)(9.2a)QS=QS(Ps)(9.2b)QD=QS(9.3c)Ps Pb=s(9.4d)subsidy Payment reducing the buyers price below the sellers price;i.e.,a negative tax.Chapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets27 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.THE IMPACT OF A TAX OR SUBSIDY9.6Effect of a$1.00-per-gallon tax:QD=150 25Pb(Demand)QS=60+20Ps(Supply)QD=QS(Supply must equal demand)Pb Ps=1.00(Government must receive$1.00/gallon)150 25Pb=60+20Ps Pb=Ps+1.00150 25Pb=60+20Ps20Ps+25Ps=150 25 6045Ps=65,or Ps=1.44Q=150 (25)(2.44)=150 61,or Q=89 bg/yrAnnual revenue from the tax tQ=(1.00)(89)=$89 billion per yearDeadweight loss:(1/2)x($1.00/gallon)x(11 billion gallons/year=$5.5 billion per yearChapter 9:The Analysis of Competitive Markets28 of 28Copyright 2009 Pearson Education,Inc.Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,8e.THE IMPACT OF A TAX OR SUBSIDY9.6Gasoline demand:QD=150 25PGasoline supply:QS=60+20PThe price of gasoline at the pump increases from$2.00 per gallon to$2.44,and the quantity sold falls from 100 to 89 bg/yr.Annual revenue from the tax is(1.00)(89)=$89 billion(areas A+D).The two triangles show the deadweight loss of$5.5 billion per year.Impact of$1 Gasoline TaxFigure 9.20

注意事项

本文(微观经济学英文课件:ch09 The Analysis of Competitive Markets)为本站会员(努力****83)主动上传,装配图网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。 若此文所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知装配图网(点击联系客服),我们立即给予删除!

温馨提示:如果因为网速或其他原因下载失败请重新下载,重复下载不扣分。




关于我们 - 网站声明 - 网站地图 - 资源地图 - 友情链接 - 网站客服 - 联系我们

copyright@ 2023-2025  zhuangpeitu.com 装配图网版权所有   联系电话:18123376007

备案号:ICP2024067431-1 川公网安备51140202000466号


本站为文档C2C交易模式,即用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,本站只是中间服务平台,本站所有文档下载所得的收益归上传人(含作者)所有。装配图网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。若文档所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知装配图网,我们立即给予删除!